Click here to Visit the RBI’s new website

publications

PDF document (297 kb)
Date : Feb 04, 2005
Dynamics of Market Structure and Competitiveness of the Banking Sector in India and its Impact on Output and Prices of Banking Services
Kaushik Bhattacharya and Abhiman Das*

The paper examines the nature and the extent of changes in the market concentration in the Indian banking sector and their possible implications on prices and output of banking services. The first part of the paper attempts to measure market concentration in banking in India in alternative ways from 1989-90 to 2000-01. In contrast to earlier empirical applications on banking, it focuses on both static and dynamic measures of market concentration. The paper finds a strong evidence of change in the market structure in banking in India. Interestingly, results reveal that a major part of the change in market structure occurred during the early 1990s. Despite a spate of mergers during the late 1990s, market concentration was not significantly affected. It is also observed that the different concentration ratios rank the changes similarly over time.

The second part of the paper analyses the possible impact of changes in banking market structure on prices and output of this sector during the same period. It is demonstrated that measurement problem of real output pertaining to banking sector in the national income data could be severe. The implied inflation as obtained through the GDP deflator for the banking sector in India led to unbelievable measures of inflation for banking services, casting some doubt on the methodology adopted. Alternatively, proxy price measures based on the spread appear to be more consistent with the changes in market structure in India during the late 1990s. The paper argues that the favourable market structure in India could be one important factor that led to a reduction in the ‘prices’ of banking services after the administered interest regime was lifted.

JEL Classification : D40, G21, L11, L89

Key Words : Concentration, Competition, Banking

* The authors are working as Assistant Advisers in the Monetary Policy Department and Department of Statistical Analysis and Computer Services, respectively. The authors wish to express their sincere thanks to Prof. Esfandiar Maasoumi, Department of Economics, Southern Methodist University, Dallas, Texas, and Prof. Mark Flannery, University of Florida, Department of Finance, Gainesville, for their insightful comments, which led to substantial improvement of the exposition of an earlier draft. The views expressed in this paper are the authors’ own. The authors bear full responsibility for any errors that remain.

Introduction

The role of competition in ushering economic efficiency has been extensively examined in the literature. In view of globalisation and renewed interest in shaping appropriate competition policies in many countries, the issue has once again become germane (Neumann, 2001). A major requirement for enhancing competition in an economy is the removal or minimisation of entry barriers. An important source of removing them is to ensure the availability of cheap finances, which inter alia, is easier to meet in the presence of a thriving and competitive banking sector. Theoretical results demonstrate that monopolistic market power of banks raises the opportunity costs of capital and thus, tends to make financing more expensive (Smith, 1998). Lack of adequate competition in banking could thus, adversely affect economic development.

To analyse competitiveness in any sector, an in-depth analysis of the structure of the market is essential. While highly concentrated markets do not necessarily imply lack of competitive behaviour, it is generally agreed that market concentration is one of the most important determinants of competitiveness (Nathan and Neavel, 1989). For banking sector, the relationship between market concentration and competitiveness has been examined in detail for many countries and the results indicated that a high concentration tends to reduce competitiveness in this sector (Gilbert, 1984). Most of the empirical evidences in the literature are, however, based on developed economies. The financial structures in many developing countries being sharply different from the developed ones, it is necessary to examine to what extent the established empirical findings in the developed economies apply to these countries, especially in an environment where financial structures are undergoing rapid and swift changes.

This paper examines the nature and the extent of changes in the structure of banking in India during the 1990s and analyses the possible impact of these changes on prices and output of banking services during the same period. The concepts of price and real output in the banking sector being fuzzy, an analytical discussion on these aspects has also been attempted. Currently, a detailed examination of these issues is relevant because the economic reforms in India during the 1990s ushered in phenomenal changes in the Indian banking sector. The new regime, in sharp contrast to the earlier regime that thrived on banking through public sector, is perceived as more accommodative towards competition. A fundamental change in this context during the second half of the 1990s had been the liberalisation of the earlier administered interest rate regime. Besides that, other significant policy measures included reduction in reserve ratio, relaxation of quantitative restrictions assets/liability composition and removal of some of the major barriers to entry into the financial system. The new policy framework also entailed considerable institutional reforms, including new laws and regulations governing the financial sector, the restructuring and privatisation of banks, and the adoption of indirect instruments of monetary policy. In the current regime, banks enjoy almost full freedom in pricing their products. Furthermore, a spate of new entries of private Indian and foreign banks and mergers among some of the existing players during the second half of the 1990s is expected to usher in significant changes in the structure of the banking sector in India.

The changes in the market structure of firms could be examined through alternative measures. Recent survey of Bikker and Haaf (2001a) lists 10 such measures proposed and used in the literature. Among these, the more popularly used ones are k-Bank Concentration Ratios and Herfindahl-Hirschman Index (HHI). The Lorenz Ratio (Gini Coefficient), a popular measure in the literature on income inequality, is also used to measure industrial concentration. In India, some of these measures have been used by the official agencies to address similar problems.1 It may, however, be noted that the scope of these popular measures is somewhat limited. For example, the HHI and the Gini coefficient are based on the variance of market shares. So far as market concentration is concerned, policy makers are in most cases not interested in the variance per se, but at the tails of the distribution of market shares. Although some of the measures listed by Bikker and Haaf (2001a) attempt to address these problems, all of them ignore the inherent dynamics associated in this process. To analyse competitiveness in an industry, specification of a full dynamic framework is necessary to gain sufficient hold on the market in the long run, while firms may initiate price wars, resulting in apparently misleading changes in the short-run concentration profiles. Although the dynamic aspects of concentration have been addressed in the literature, earlier studies focussed primarily on a descriptive analysis of the changes in indices of concentration from year to year in specific industries and related it to 'competitiveness' measured in alternative ways.

Recent advances in the literature have, however, explicitly focussed on the dynamic aspects of concentration measures. Borrowing concepts from the related literature on income mobility, Maasoumi and Slottje (2002) have classified measures of industrial concentration based on generalised entropies, obtained asymptotic distributions for these measures and applied them on the US steel industries. Empirical results reveal that the incorporation of the dynamic aspects could lead to changes in inferences drawn from more traditional static measures. As this development is a nascent one, the empirical relevance of these developments in the banking sector is yet to be examined.

So far as banking sector is concerned, our study is different from the earlier studies in two respects. First, we examine the changes in concentration in the banking sector in India in both static and dynamic framework and compare them empirically. While the static framework employs standard measures of concentration, in the dynamic frameworks, we measure these changes through generalised entropy measures as developed by Maasoumi (1986) and Maasoumi and Zandvakili (1990). Wherever possible, results are compared to those obtained for other countries. Second, while examining the implications of changes in the concentration profiles on competitiveness and on the prices and output of the banking sector, we demonstrate that standard measures of prices and output as per the national accounts statistics could provide a distorted picture. We argue that alternative proxies of ‘price’ based on the spread between the lending and the deposit rates appear to be more consistent with the changes in the concentration profiles of banks in India during this period.

The plan of the paper is as follows: Section I presents a brief review of literature on measuring concentration, with special reference to dynamic measures of concentration. Section II describes the empirical evidence on changes in the structure of banking sector in India. Section III attempts to analyse the possible impact of these changes on prices and quantities of the financial intermediation services. Finally, Section IV concludes the paper with some critical comments, focussing on policy aspects.

Section I A Brief Review of Literature

So far as measur ement of market concentration is concerned, many of the existing results on income inequality could be readily translated. Drawing analogies from the literature on income inequality, the ‘inequality’ in the share of sales (or output or share of industry employees) of individual firms in an industry has been specified as appropriate empirical measure of market concentration. These measures have been estimated and related them to competitiveness measured in alternative ways.

In the income inequality literature, inequality has also been examined in a dynamic framework. These mobility studies have been compared to videotapes on inequality as against a spot picture provided by the static measures. Recently, attempts have been made to translate the framework to measure market concentration.

Accordingly, Subsection I.1 reviews the static measures of concentration and Subsection I.2 does that for the dynamic measures.

I.1 Static Measures of Concentration

In the static inequality literature, different inequality measures do not necessarily imply the same ordering of distributions. Either explicitly or implicitly, almost all these measures or orderings are based on a weighted average of the income (or, wealth) vector of individuals (or, households). The disagreement occurs in the specification of the weights. The disagreement is irrelevant, if there are ‘good’ reasons to demonstrate the superiority of one measure over others. The ‘good’ reasons could be specified in alternative ways. One way is to identify a few desirable properties that a measure on inequality should satisfy. Some of these properties are symmetry, continuity, invariance to scalar multiplication, additive decomposability and satisfaction of transfer principle (Shorrocks, 1984). Another way is to derive an inequality measure or an ordering from a social welfare function (SWF). The SWF is specified as a function of the income (or, wealth) vector of all individuals (or, households). Thus, different income distributions can be ordered based on the SWF pertaining to them. This approach often involves specifying an axiomatic structure that such a SWF should satisfy. Subsequent task involves characterising indices or orderings that would satisfy such axioms.

Like indices of inequality, different indices of concentration put different weights over different parts of the distribution of market shares across firms and may give contradictory evidence. Let there be n firms in an industry with market shares s1, s2, …, sn. A simple but general linear form of an index of industrial concentration (IIC ) is:

Following the taxonomy of Marfels (1971), there could be four broad classes of weighing schemes: (i) unity to top k firms and zero to the rest, (ii) individual ranks of firms, (iii) firms’ own market shares or their power, and (iv) the negative of the logarithm of market shares.

The weighing scheme reflects different assessment regarding the relative impact of larger and smaller firms. Depending upon the weighing scheme, the individual measures may vary, but they may lead to similar orderings.2

As in the inequality literature, there are two ways to deal with the problem of lack of robustness with respect to weights. One way is to report 'complete rankings’’ through a class of concentration measures that reflect the sensitivity to concentration in all parts of the share distribution. Another approach is to consider 'partial but uniform’’ orderings that evaluate concentration over a restricted part, but over a larger class of evaluative functions. Whatever be the strategy, Maasoumi and Slottje (2002) argue that for transparency’s sake, it is imperative for the policymakers and analysts to declare the 'weights’’ they attach to a reduction in concentration over various parts of a distribution.

The most common measure used in the literature on market concentration has been a simple concentration index, aggregating such shares of a few top firms (say, k). These measures for banking firms are called k-Bank Concentration Ratios. There is no rule for choosing an appropriate value of k. So, the number of firms included in the concentration index is an ad hoc and an arbitrary decision. The index ranges from zero to unity. The index approaches zero for an infinite number of equally sized banks and it equals unity, if the firms included in the calculation of the concentration ratio make up the entire industry.

Another popularly used measure is the Hirfendahl-Hirschman index (HHI)3 . For n firms in an industry with market shares si ,(i=1,2, ... , n), the HHI is defined as:

HHI can be written as an increasing function of the population variance of market shares. The more 'equal' the firm’s size is, the smaller is the HHI. HHI also satisfies the well known 'transfers’’ property. By definition (1/n) <1, where n is the number of firms in an industry. The maximum concentration of unity occurs when one firm has all the sales, output, etc. Minimum of concentration (1/n) occurs when each firm has an equal share of 1/n.

Despite its popularity, HHI suffers from a few limitations. A major limitation is that distributions of market shares with radically different tail properties may have HHI of similar magnitude (Rhoades, 1995). Recently, Maasoumi and Slottje (2002) have argued that common economic phenomena like mergers between a strong and a weak firm or entries and exits only change certain parts of the distribution of market share – often the tails only. Indices based solely on 'dispersion’’ or variance, (e.g., HHI, Gini, etc.) may miss such changes. Another popular measure that shares most of the properties of HHI is the Gini ratio. The Gini ratio, in a continuous variable framework, is defined as:

where the market share of each bank is weighted by its ranking in order to ensure that the emphasis is on the absolute number of banks, and that the largest bank receives weight i=l. This index includes the number of banks in the calculation of a concentration index, because it reflects to some extent the conditions of entry into a particular industry.

(b) The Rosenbluth Index (RI) is defined as:

(5) RI=1/(n(1-G)), where G is the Gini-coefficient.

(c) The Comprehensive Industrial Concentration Index (CCI) is defined as :

It is the sum of the proportional share of the leading bank and the summation of the squares of the proportional sizes of each bank, weighted by a multiplier, reflecting the proportional size of the rest of the industry.

(d) The Hannah and Kay Index (HKI) is defined as :

where a is an elasticity parameter to be specified and intended to reflect their ideas about changes in concentration as a result of the entry or exit of banks, and the sales transfer among the different banks in the market. The freedom to choose a allows for alternative views on: what is the appropriate weighting scheme and for the option to emphasise either the upper or the lower segment of the bank size distribution. Therefore, in addition to the distribution of the banks in the market, the value of the index is sensitive to the parameter a. For ????0 , the index approaches the number of banks in the industry, and for ?????, it converges towards the reciprocal of the market share of the largest bank.

(e) The Hause Indices

i) The multiplicatively modified Hause Index takes the form:

where HHI is the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index and a is the parameter capturing the degree of collusion.

ii) Hause furthermore proposes the additively adjusted measure of concentration, which is defined as:

(f) Entropy Measure

The Entropy measure has its theoretical foundations in information theory and measures the ex-ante expected information content of a distribution. It takes the form:

Indices (a) to (g) are discussed in detail in Bikker and Haaf (2001a). It may be noted that some of the indices are based on higher moments of market shares. For example, the Comprehensive Concentration Index (CCI) could be associated with the third moment of market shares. In some cases, they are functions of market shares as well as the HHI. Some of the measures, in fact, represent broad classes. The values of a specific measure within that class will depend on specific values of certain parameters. In an empirical exercise, the choices of the values of these parameters are often not clear. Researchers typically specify a set of 'plausible' values of these parameters and examine the robustness of the obtained results.

Availability of so many indices implies that in any specific exercise, it is important to specify the underlying axiomatic structure under which the corresponding index becomes the 'best' index. In their various incarnations, axiomatic structures identify the generalised entropy (GE) as an 'ideal' family of indices. For a weighted random vector X=(X1,…,Xn)' with weights w=(w1,…,wn)' the GE concentration measure is defined as:

reciprocal inclusion probabilities. This family includes HHI, variance of logarithms, square of the coefficient of variation, and for l=0, -1, this index converges to the first and second Theil measures of information

It has been shown that Theil's second measure (l = -1) provides the most unambiguous answer to such fundamental questions as: How much of the overall concentration is due to the concentration within the rt h group? The groups could be with respect to type of product, technology, location, or the size itself. These two measures in (13) and (14) were further studied by Maasoumi and Theil (1979) with a view to determine their characteristics in terms of the moments of distributions. Let:

When z has a lognormal distribution, both indices equal - (1/2)s2. HHI can be shown to be a simple function of s2, but not of the higher moments. Thus, it can fail with departures from lognormality. The above approximate formulae can be used when the underlying distribution is not known. They allow us to see that positive skewness and leptokurtosis increase concentration, and that is more sensitive to positive skewness I 0(high sales/output groups) and fat tails (large extreme sales groups) than I-1 .

As these entropy measures appear more general and relatively easy to implement, their use in the context of measuring market concentration has often been suggested. This is because entropy is shown as a much richer function of all the moments of a distribution, and more closely identifies it than any single moment such as variance or HHI.

I.2 Dynamic Measures of Concentration

The dynamic measures of concentration emerge from the realisation that it is misleading to consider states of a market at only single points in time. Transitory conditions may mislead and become difficult to disentangle when looking at several periods/situations. It is thus, desirable to consider market concentration over several periods, and to develop a dynamic concentration profile, following the concepts of mobility as in Maasoumi and Zandvakili (1990).

Let denote sales/output of firm i, (i=1,…,N), in period t=1,…,T.XitWe denote the vector ,....Xt =(X1t ,X2t ,XNt)¢. Let Si=Si (Xi1,…, XiT) be the ‘permanent’ or 'aggregate’’ sales of firm i over T periods. Of course, one can define the aggregates over periods 1 to T¢£ T, say, and develop a mobility profile as T¢ approaches T. Then(17)S =(S1,…, Sn)¢is the vector of aggregate sales for a chosen time frame. Following Maasoumi (1986), the following type of aggregation functions are justified on the basis that they minimize the generalized entropy distance between S and all of the T 'sales’’ distributions:

where at is the weight attached to sales in period t, Sa t=1. The elasticity of substitution of sales/output across time is constant at a=1/ (1+b). The case b = –1 corresponds to perfect inter-temporal substitution, which subsumes Shorrocks’ analysis for certain weights. This case is also the most common formulation of the 'permanent income’’ concept in economics. In this context, we can think of the concept as 'permanent output’’, or 'expected sales’’.

Mobility is measured as the ratio of 'long run’’ concentration occurring when the period of examination is extended, and a measure of short run concentration. The latter may be represented by any one period of interest, or a weighted average of the single period concentrations. We might think of this as a notion of 'competition enhancing’’ mobility, a welfare theoretic base in favour of large, non-concentrated markets.4 The extension of the time interval is meant to reflect the dynamics and smooth out the transitory or business cycle effects in the industry. Shorrocks (1978) proposed the following mobility measures:

where I() is the 'inequality’’ measure. For convex inequality measures I(), 0£M£1 is easily verified when S is the linear 'permanent output’’ function. For other aggregator functions see Maasoumi and Zandvakili (1990). A priori, there would be no reason for an analyst to give unequal weights to different years under study. Nevertheless, Shorrocks (1978) suggests the ratio of year t income to total income over the T periods as suitable values for at s. We consider both weighting schemes here.5

Section II Empirical Analysis

Compared to many other developing countries, India has an extensive banking network. Before an empirical analysis, a brief discussion on the taxonomy and the historical development of the structure of the Indian banking market would be essential.6 Accordingly, Subsection II.1 presents such a review in brief. Subsections II.2 and II.3 present results based on static and dynamic measures, respectively.

II.1 Taxonomy and Historical Development

The scheduled banking structure in India consists of banks that are included in the Second Schedule of the Reserve Bank of India Act, 1934. These scheduled banks are divided in two groups, viz., scheduled commercial banks and scheduled co-operative banks. This study is restricted to scheduled commercial banks that account for more than 90 per cent of banking business in India. For analytical purposes, the scheduled commercial banks could be further classified into four groups, viz., public sector banks, Indian private sector banks, regional rural banks and foreign banks. Among the public sector banks, official reports generally indicate results separately for State Bank of India (SBI) and its Associates and Other Nationalized Banks, due to the large size of the former.

So far as banking is concerned, the year 1969 marked a watershed, during which fourteen major banks in India were nationalised. At that time, there were 73 scheduled commercial banks in India, of which 15 were foreign banks. Due to strong emphasis on increasing the savings rate of the economy, the 1970s and 1980s experienced phenomenal growth in the banking network that spanned the entire country. As a result, though the absolute number of scheduled commercial banks (other than regional rural banks) did not increase much (78 as at end-March 1990, of which 22 were foreign banks), the number of bank branches increased from 8,262 in 1969 to 59,752 as at end-March 1990, resulting in a very high annual compound growth rate of 18.8 per cent in deposit mobilisation, from Rs.4,646 crore as at end-March 1969 to Rs.1,73,515 crore as at end-March 1990. The Indian Government has historically undertaken a number of extensive and elaborate policy initiatives to extend the outreach of formal credit systems to the rural population. One of the major initiatives taken was the establishment of Regional Rural Banks (RRBs) in 1975. These policy initiatives during 1970-90 had a far-reaching impact on the functional reach and geographical spread of banking in India. However, this period is also characterised by widespread control, limiting the scope of competition. Interest rates were strictly administered and had multiple layers. On the lending side, the focus was on priority sectors. The banking market during this period was also highly segmented.

Following the balance of payments crisis in India during the early 1990s, the earlier regime experienced a radical change. A major change was to shift away from the earlier administered rates towards market determined ones. On the lending side, the deregulation began in 1994 with emphasis on the development of money, Government securities and foreign exchange markets. The conduct of monetary policy also slowly moved away from the use of direct instruments of monetary control to indirect measures such as open market operations. Banks were given freedom to set their Prime Lending Rates and to devise their own lending policies. On the liabilities side, the entire gamut of deposit rates – except on savings deposits – were deregulated, and the banks were given freedom to offer different interest rates for different maturities/ size-groups. Interest rates on Government securities were made market-determined. The refinance facility of Reserve Bank of India (RBI) was also rationalised and sector specific refinance facilities were de-emphasised. During 1997, another overriding development with far reaching implications was, however, the reactivation of the Bank Rate, which was linked to other interest rates including the Reserve Bank’s refinance rate. During this period, banks were also permitted to rationalise their existing branch network viz., to shift their existing branches within the same locality, open certain type of specialised branches, convert the existing non-viable rural branches into satellite offices, etc.

Table 1 presents the movement of select banking indicators during last two decades. It is observed that the decade 1992-02 is marked with significant increase in the banking business by Indian private banks. While the deposits of Indian public sector banks grew at an annual compound growth rate of around 15.55 per cent during 1992-02, the same for Indian private banks grew at an annual compound growth for around 28.57 per cent. In the case of bank credit also, a similar pattern is observed.

Table 1: Movement of Select Banking Indicators

during 1982-92 to 1992-02

Bank-groups

Growth in number

Compound growth

Compound growth

of branches

of deposits

of bank credit

1982-92

1992-02

1982-92

1992-02

1982-92

1992-02

State Bank of India & its

Associates

26.54

7.69

16.18

15.48

14.64

15.32

Nationalised Banks

32.64

3.41

15.15

15.59

13.81

15.23

Regional Rural Banks

60.09

-1.82

27.46

23.07

21.64

16.52

Indian Private Banks

-5.87

23.67

15.57

28.57

17.85

28.23

Foreign Banks

12.58

17.93

25.91

13.46

21.53

19.29

Total

35.33

4.80

16.12

16.75

14.83

17.00


The liberalisation measures adopted during the beginning of the study period, attempted to reduce entry barriers by discarding the earlier licence-permit regime. As a consequence, there were a number of new entrants in the banking business during this period. Table 2 lists the new arrivals of banks in India between 1989-90 and 2000-01 chronologically. It is interesting to note that during the first few years, there were no new arrivals. The early 1990s was the period of consolidation after the economic debacle following the balance of payments crisis experienced by India during the year 1990-91. The arrivals started during early 1994 after the crisis was effectively tackled and in consequence, the pace of liberalisation in the Indian financial sector accelerated. Table 2 reveals the arrival of 33 new banks during this period, among which 24 are of foreign origin. It is also interesting to note that the arrival of the foreign banks accelerated during the later period.

Table 2: Entry of New Banks during 1990-2001

BankName

Dateof

Ownership

BankName

Dateof

Ownership

Opening

Category

Opening

Category

Barclays Bank

8/10/90

Foreign Bank

Bank of Ceylon

30/10/95

Foreign Bank

Sanwa Bank

20/12/90

Foreign Bank

Commerz Bank

1/12/95

Foreign Bank

UTIBank

28/02/94

IndianPrivate

Siam Commercial

14/12/95

Foreign Bank

Bank

Bank

IndusIndBank

2/04/94

IndianPrivate

Bank International

6/04/96

Foreign Bank

Bank

Indonesia

ICICI Bank

17/05/94

IndianPrivate

Arab Bangladesh

6/04/96

Foreign Bank

Bank

Bank

INGBank

1/06/94

Foreign Bank

Chinatrust

8/04/96

Foreign Bank

Commercial Bank

Global Trust Bank

6/09/94

IndianPrivate

Cho Hung Bank

6/05/96

Foreign Bank

Bank

Chase Manhattan Bank

21/09/94

Foreign Bank

Fuji Bank

20/05/96

Foreign Bank

State Bank of Mauritius

1/11/94

Foreign Bank

Krung Thai Bank

6/01/97

Foreign Bank

HDFC Bank

5/01/95

IndianPrivate

Overseas Chinese

31/01/97

Foreign Bank

Bank

Bank

Centurion Bank

13/01/95

IndianPrivate

Commercial Bank

12/03/97

Foreign Bank

Bank

of Korea

DBS Bank

15/03/95

Foreign Bank

Sumitomo Bank

20/06/97

Foreign Bank

Bank of Punjab

5/04/95

IndianPrivate

Hanil Bank

5/07/97

Foreign Bank

Bank

TimesBank

8/06/95

IndianPrivate

Toronto-Dominion

25/10/97

Foreign Bank

Bank

Bank

Dresdner Bank

21/08/95

Foreign Bank

Bank Muscat

9/09/98

Foreign Bank

International

IDBI Bank

28/09/95

IndianPrivate

Morgan Guaranty

24/12/98

Foreign Bank

Bank

Trust K. B. C. Bank

15/02/99

Foreign Bank


The new environment in banking demanded restructuring and reorienting the policy goals of banks. One way to adapt to the new environment was through mergers. It may be noted that though bank mergers were common phenomenon in many developed and developing countries, they were comparatively new in India during the 1990s.7 Table 3 presents the list of mergers and acquisitions among the banks. It lists 18 such mergers. Once again, it may be noted that 10 of the mergers and restructuring took place during the second half of the 1990s. To understand the nature of these mergers in detail, the type of merger has also been indicated in Table 3. Most of the mergers took place either between two private sector banks or two public sector banks. Among the public sector banks, generally a 'weak' bank had been merged with a 'strong' bank. Thus, if one considers public sector or private sector as a group, the effect of merger on bank performance may not be very significant. In one or two cases, it is observed that a non-banking financial company had been merged with a bank.

Table 3 : Mergers and Acquisitions of Banks: 1985-2002

Name of the merging entity

No. of

Name of the merged entity

Date/Year of

Branches

merger

United Industrial Bank

145

Allahabad Bank

31/10/89

Bank of Tamil Nadu

99

Indian Overseas Bank

20/02/90

Bank of Thanjavur

156

Indian Bank

20/02/90

Parur Central Bank

51

Bank of India

20/02/90

Purbachal Bank

40

Central Bank of India

29/08/90

Bank of Karad

48

Bank of India

2/05/92

New Bank of India

591

Punjab National Bank

1993

BCCI (Mumbai)

1

State Bank of India

1993

Kashinath Seth Bank

11

State Bank of India

1/01/96

Bari Doab Bank

10

Oriental Bank of Commerce

8/04/97

Punjab Co-operative Bank

9

Oriental Bank of Commerce

8/04/97

20th Century Finance

Centurion Bank

1/01/98

Bareilly Corporation Bank

65

Bank of Baroda

3/06/99

Sikkim Bank

7

Union Bank of India

22/12/99

Times Bank

10

HDFC Bank

26/02/00

Bank of Madura

270

ICICI Bank

10/03/01

Sakura Bank

2

Sumitomo Bank

1/04/01

Morgan Gurantee Trust

1

Chase Manhattan Bank

10/11/01

II.2 Changes in the Market Structure in Indian Banking: Static Measures

The evidences in Tables 1–3 reflect the changes in the structure of Indian banking. We now attempt to examine these changes in detail by measuring the changes in different concentration indices over the years. We estimated the measures of concentration at industry as well as at bank-group level with respect to total assets, total deposits and total income. However, for the sake of brevity, we have presented the values at industry level based on total assets.8

From an analytical point of view, before discussing the trends of the various concentration measures in the post-reform period, we present a brief statistical profile of various concentration measures (Table 4).9 The first impression demonstrates the diverging results yielded by the various concentration measures when applied to the same underlying market. Even a short glance reveals the wide spread in these values. The results show clearly that not only does the range of possible values differ strongly across the indices, but so do the values of the indices within this range. For instance, the value is high for the CRk and low for the HHI and Rosenbluth index.

Table 5 presents the trends in various concentration measures during 1989-90 to 2000-01. Note that as these figures are population figures (scheduled co-operative banks are excluded, we interpret scheduled commercial banks as the ‘population’), computations of standard errors are not necessary. In general, concentration indices, as presented in Table 5, appear to be inversely related to the number of banks. This is owing to the well-known weakness of concentration indices, namely, their dependency on the size of the banking market. The value of the k-bank concentration ratios (for various values of k) always exceeds the value of HHI, since the latter gives less prominence to the markets shares (the weights again being market shares) than the former (unit weights). Irrespective of the choice of the concentration index, measures of concentration have declined in

Table 4: Average Measures of Concentration: 1989-90 to 2000-01

Index

Range

Parameters

Typical features

Avg.

Std.

CV

type

Value

Dev.

GINI

0.736

0.012

1.631

Takes only large banks

0.250

0.020

7.931

CR1

0 <

1

into account;

0.311

0.025

8.160

CR2

CR

k£

arbitrary cut off

0.472

0.032

6.690

CR5

0.628

0.044

6.940

CR10

HHI

1/n £ HHI

£

1

Considers all banks; sensitive

0.085

0.012

13.835

to entrance of new banks

HTI

0 < HTI

£

1

Emphasis on absolute

0.050

0.005

9.805

number of banks

Rosen-

0 < RI

£

1

Sensitive to changes in

0.044

0.007

15.753

bluth

the size distribution of

small banks

CCI

0 < CCI £

1

Addresses relative dispersion

0.293

0.023

7.810

and absolute magnitude;

suitable for cartel markets

CI

0.745

0.013

1.700

HKI

HKI£

n

a = 0.005

Stresses influence small banks

86.880

11.292

12.998

(1/s 1) £

a = 0.25

62.355

8.264

13.253

a = 5

5.686

0.542

9.529

a = 10

Stresses influence large banks

4.688

0.399

8.501

Hause

0 <

£

1

a = 0.25

Suitable for highly collusive

0.138

0.019

13.481

Hm

index

markets

a = 1

0.085

0.012

13.947

a = 2

Suitable for not collusive

0.085

0.012

13.837

markets

Entropy

0 £ E £

log

n

Based on expected

3.282

0.152

4.633

information content of a

distribution


the post-reform period. Two different patterns are very clear: (a) there exists a uniform ordering/trend across various measures, (b) although reform process reduced concentration in the industry, the speed of reduction has been noticeably slow. However, the role of financial liberalisation in lowering concentration is clearly established. It is interesting to note that the major part of the change in the structure had occurred during the early 1990s. Thus, the spate of mergers during the late 1990s did not change the market structure significantly.

Table 5 : Movement of Various Measures of

Concentration: 1989-90 to 2000-01

Year

No. of

GINI

1-Bank

HHI

HTI

RI

CCI

CC

Entropy

Banks

Ratio

1990

75

0.757

0.281

0.103

0.058

0.055

0.328

0.767

3.057

1991

77

0.757

0.279

0.102

0.057

0.054

0.325

0.767

3.079

1992

77

0.750

0.278

0.101

0.055

0.052

0.324

0.760

3.105

1993

76

0.733

0.261

0.091

0.052

0.049

0.306

0.742

3.174

1994

74

0.721

0.256

0.089

0.050

0.048

0.301

0.731

3.192

1995

83

0.725

0.237

0.079

0.049

0.044

0.282

0.734

3.300

1996

92

0.738

0.241

0.079

0.047

0.041

0.283

0.746

3.340

1997

97

0.734

0.233

0.075

0.045

0.039

0.274

0.742

3.404

1998

100

0.734

0.226

0.072

0.045

0.038

0.267

0.742

3.437

1999

100

0.732

0.234

0.075

0.046

0.037

0.273

0.740

3.433

2000

100

0.729

0.236

0.074

0.045

0.037

0.273

0.736

3.441

2001

99

0.727

0.244

0.077

0.045

0.037

0.279

0.735

3.425


To establish the observed first pattern, Table 6 presents product-moment correlations among various concentration indices in India over time10. Results based on almost all the pairs are similar, displaying a high degree of correlation. The strongest correlations are found between CR1 and CR2, RI and CR3, CCI and CR1, HHI and CR1. These results clearly demonstrate that, at least in the Indian context, the behaviour of various concentration indices is very similar. Thus, our results indicate that though a host of measures for market concentration are available, an empirical application is unlikely to yield different rankings of a single economy over time. Our results thus, compliment the results of Bikker and Haaf (2001a), who did a similar exercise over space. The observed correlations are, however, not very strong when the measures are based on either total deposits or total income , indicating that some differences could exist across the variable, which is used to compute the size distribution (e.g., asset, deposit and income)11. This is not unlikely because the markets for different bank products could be sharply different and the largest banks in one market may not be necessarily so in other ones.

Finally, we compare concentration measures of Indian banking industry to those in a few other developed economies based on the results of Bikker and Haaf (2001a). Bikker and Haaf (2001) observed high market concentration in Denmark, Greece, Netherlands and Switzerland and low market concentration in France, Germany, Italy,

Table 6 : Product Moment Correlations among Different

Measures of Concentration

GINI

HHI

RI

CR1

CR2

CR3

CR4

CCI

CC

ENT

GINI

1.00

HHI

0.74

1.00

RI

0.66

0.97

1.00

CR 1

0.73

0.99

0.94

1.00

CR 2

0.76

0.99

0.97

0.99

1.00

CR 3

0.72

0.98

0.99

0.95

0.98

1.00

CR 4

0.70

0.95

0.99

0.91

0.95

0.99

1.00

CCI

0.73

0.99

0.97

0.99

0.99

0.98

0.95

1.00

CC

0.99

0.79

0.72

0.78

0.81

0.77

0.75

0.78

1.00

ENT

-0.66

-0.98

-0.99

-0.95

-0.97

-0.99

-0.99

-0.98

-0.72

1.00


Luxembourg and the US. Table 7 juxtaposes the HHI and CRk (for k=3, 5 and 10) measures based on total assets for India along with similar measures for 20 countries during the year 1997. It is interesting to observe that market oncentration in banking in India appears to be low as compared to other countries. For example, India ranks joint 8th (with Spain) with respect to HHI and joint 6th (with UK) with respect to CR3 measure.

Table 7: Concentration Indices for

21 Countries, based on Total Assets: 1997

Countries

HHI

No. of banks

CR3

CR5

CR10

Australia

0.14

0.57

0.77

0.90

31

Austria

0.14

0.53

0.64

0.77

78

Belgium

0.12

0.52

0.75

0.87

79

Canada

0.14

0.54

0.82

0.94

44

Denmark

0.17

0.67

0.80

0.91

91

France

0.05

0.30

0.45

0.64

336

Germany

0.03

0.22

0.31

0.46

1803

Greece

0.20

0.66

0.82

0.94

22

India

0.08

0.34

0.43

0.62

97

Ireland

0.17

0.65

0.73

0.84

30

Italy

0.04

0.27

0.40

0.54

331

Japan

0.06

0.39

0.49

0.56

140

Luxembourg

0.03

0.20

0.30

0.49

118

Netherlands

0.23

0.78

0.87

0.93

45

Norway

0.12

0.56

0.67

0.81

35

Portugal

0.09

0.40

0.57

0.82

40

Spain

0.08

0.45

0.56

0.69

140

Sweden

0.12

0.53

0.73

0.92

21

Switzerland

0.26

0.72

0.77

0.82

325

UK

0.06

0.34

0.47

0.68

186

US

0.02

0.15

0.23

0.38

717

Source : Except India, other figures have been taken from Bikker and Haaf (2001a).


II.3 Changes in the Market Structure in Indian Banking: Dynamic Measures

In the case of computing generalised entropy measures, the permanent assets (deposits/income) are computed based on µ t weights. These weights used here are the ratio of mean assets at µt time t to the mean assets over the entire M periods. In our computations, the substitutions parameter b is restricted by the relation -g = 1 + b. We computed four different aggregator functions corresponding to four inequality measures with -g = V = (2, 1, 0.5, 0.0). V = 0.0 and 1.0 correspond to Theil’s first and second inequality measures, respectively, combined with the linear and the Cobb-Douglas forms of the aggregator function. Table 8 provides the annual short-run inequalities, the inequalities in the aggregated (long-run) assets, and the assets stability measures RM. Decomposition of each ‘between’ and ‘within’ groups is also presented.

Short-run inequality in Table 8 has generally decreased. Surprisingly, the inequality has not become greater with larger degrees of relative inequality aversion (V). For V other than 2, the ‘within-group’ component of short-run inequalities is dominant. However, the absolute values of both ‘within-group’ and ‘between-group’ inequality measures have recorded a significant decline over the 12 years period.

The long-run inequality has recorded relatively less volatility. In all the years, the values of Ig(S) have decreased and in most cases they are dominated by ‘within-group’ component measures. In some cases, the long-run inequality measures are higher than the short-run component. It may be mentioned that these relative values are somewhat sensitive to the size distribution. The corresponding stability measures showed somewhat different pattern. Although, the stability measures have fallen over the years, they have been highly dominated by ‘between-group’ component and the impact of ‘within-group’ has been marginalised. Thus, there is a tendency for the profiles of the banks to fall, and then level off in the years to come. These patterns are robust with respect to the choice of aggregation function, size-adjustment and inequality measure.

Table 8: Empirical Values of Generalised Entropy Measures

Year

Shortrun

Longrun

Stability

Overall

Between

Within

Overall

Between

Within

Overall

Between

Within

Degree of inequality aversion = 2.0

1990-93

2.028

0.891

1.137

2.068

0.904

1.164

1.020

1.014

0.006

1990-95

1.744

0.762

0.982

1.877

0.794

1.084

1.076

1.042

0.035

1990-97

0.959

0.641

0.319

1.243

0.696

0.547

1.296

1.086

0.210

1990-99

0.777

0.544

0.233

1.036

0.620

0.416

1.333

1.139

0.194

1990-01

0.696

0.475

0.221

0.904

0.564

0.340

1.299

1.187

0.112

1996-01

0.552

0.354

0.198

0.581

0.362

0.219

1.053

1.022

0.030

Degree of inequality aversion = 1.0

1990-93

1.333

0.507

0.826

1.141

0.375

0.766

0.856

0.740

0.116

1990-95

1.254

0.460

0.794

1.074

0.348

0.727

0.856

0.755

0.102

1990-97

1.175

0.409

0.766

1.016

0.311

0.705

0.865

0.759

0.105

1990-99

1.134

0.364

0.770

0.982

0.276

0.706

0.866

0.758

0.108

1990-01

1.112

0.328

0.784

0.972

0.246

0.726

0.874

0.750

0.124

1996-01

1.052

0.273

0.780

0.956

0.232

0.724

0.909

0.852

0.057

Degree of inequality aversion = 0.5

1990-93

1.068

0.425

0.643

1.063

0.422

0.641

0.995

0.993

0.002

1990-95

1.017

0.394

0.623

1.008

0.387

0.621

0.991

0.982

0.009

1990-97

0.966

0.357

0.609

0.955

0.344

0.611

0.989

0.965

0.024

1990-99

0.936

0.323

0.613

0.921

0.305

0.616

0.984

0.945

0.039

1990-01

0.921

0.294

0.627

0.905

0.272

0.633

0.983

0.927

0.055

1996-01

0.879

0.251

0.628

0.879

0.247

0.632

1.000

0.981

0.019

Degree of inequality aversion = 0.0

1990-93

1.147

0.438

0.709

1.331

0.506

0.825

1.160

1.155

0.006

1990-95

1.093

0.397

0.696

1.262

0.458

0.804

1.155

1.153

0.001

1990-97

1.041

0.358

0.683

1.194

0.405

0.789

1.147

1.132

0.015

1990-99

1.011

0.333

0.678

1.143

0.358

0.785

1.131

1.075

0.055

1990-01

0.997

0.324

0.673

1.115

0.320

0.795

1.118

0.988

0.130

1996-01

0.955

0.303

0.652

1.063

0.271

0.792

1.113

0.893

0.220


The fact that the profiles are becoming flatter is an indication that, although there have been some transitory movements in the size distribution of assets, there is a lack of any permanent equalization. Further more, while some equalisation has taken place within each group of banks, inequality between groups has been noticeably high.

Section III Impact on Prices and Quantities

In this section, we examine the possible impact of the changes in concentration on the prices and output in the banking sector. It may be noted that as we have limited observations (e.g., annual data only), the causal nature of market structure and performance is difficult to establish. It is well known that even in a market structure that is apparently monopolistic, competitive prices may exist due to threat of entry. Our arguments in this section are, therefore, not definitive. However, despite limitations, our observations in this section may turn out to be useful in reconciling the conceptual anomalies and as a consequence, in forming the suitable hypotheses.

The literature that discusses the relationship between market structure and competitiveness is voluminous. The survey of Bikker and Haaf (2001a) also covers this area, focussing on different theoretical and empirical approaches with special reference to banking. To link concentration and competitiveness empirically, one needs to specify and estimate appropriate models based on panel data.1 2 In the panel data models, disaggregated bank specific data on some ‘performance’ measures is regressed on the bank’s own market share, market concentration at the aggregate level and other ‘control’ factors. The ‘performance’ measures are typically based on profits or prices. While data on profits are taken from the profit and loss accounts of banks, appropriate bank specific interest rates are supposed to be a proxy for the prices. Empirical findings suggest monopolistic competition; competition appears to be weaker in the local markets and stronger in the international markets. The relationship for the impact of market structure on competition seems to support the conventional view that concentration impairs competitiveness.

It may be noted that whatever be the theoretical structure specified, the empirical measures for ‘prices’ in banking are not very clear. As there is no clear common methodology for measuring prices and output of financial intermediation services and SNA 1993 recognizes this as a problem area, Subsection III.1 discusses a few common conceptual problems in the literature, and in this context, emphasises that the direct use of select interest rates as a ‘price’ measure may not be conceptually appropriate. Arguing on the basis of the user cost approach, we suggest the use of spread as ‘price’ measures for banking. Subsection III.2 reviews alternative empirical estimates of prices and output for this sector in India during the reference period, and attempts to relate it to our earlier findings. In particular, it compares inflation measures for banking based on traditional GDP deflators and spread, and finds the latter to be more consistent with the changing patterns of market structure of banking in India.

III.1 Conceptual Problems in Measurement of Prices and Output of Financial Intermediation Services

It may be noted that measurements of prices and output of services are difficult because services are produced and consumed at the same point of time. Also, prices of services are more dispersed across regions because of their non-tradable nature (Grilliches, 1992). Besides these common problems, measurements of prices and output of financial services are further limited due to many conceptual problems that have not yet been resolved satisfactorily. First, it is not clear whether financial services are attached to the financial instruments, accompanying the transactions or to the monetary units being transacted. Most of the activities of a bank involve processing documents (such as cheques and loan payments) and dealing with customers (Benston et al., 1982). Consequently, previous researchers have used the average number of deposit and loan accounts serviced per month as their unit of output to measure the customer related services. Alternatively, Fixler (1993) has argued that the amount of financial services sold by a bank can be more appropriately measured by the money balances in the various products. Secondly, it is not clear which financial services are relevant to the measurement of output: those attached to assets, liabilities or both? This question concerns the precise identification of inputs and outputs.

The debate on measurement of bank output mainly revolves around the status of demand deposit related financial services . Demand deposits have the characteristics of both input and output. On one hand, they are like ‘raw materials’ in the financial intermediation process and are used for ‘production’ of loans and investment; on the other hand, a host of ‘final’ services (e.g., maintenance of money, free cheque facilities, etc.) are attached to them. Till now, consensus regarding the status of demand deposit has not emerged in the literature. Thirdly, many of the financial services are jointly produced with a sequence of barter transactions and are typically assigned to a bundle of financial services, the ‘pricing’ of which is difficult and is often apparently ‘free’ in nature.

These conceptual problems imply that any measurement of the services provided by banks in real terms would be difficult. In the absence of precise measures of prices and output in banking, researchers have attempted to resolve the problem indirectly by developing certain indicators – either for production or for the prices. A few common indicators have been used widely in official statistics, for conversion of value added of the banking sector from current prices to constant prices. In many cases, the indicators have focused on a single aspect related to the sector, concentrating on a simple ratio-variable and hoping that other related variables move proportionally to the one proposed.

Till the end of 1980s, the United States’ (US) Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) used one such indicator for conversion of gross product originating (GPO) in the banking sector from current prices to constant prices. To do that, the benchmark value of GPO at current prices was determined for a particular year. Output for subsequent years was calculated by extrapolating the benchmark value by a factor based on the ‘number of persons engaged in production’, the implicit assumption in the method being that there had not been any growth in labour productivity in banking! When applied, the estimates showed very small real output growth in the banking sector, so small that many economists believed that the method underestimated real output of the banking sector in the US economy (Fixler, 1993). So far as the other countries are concerned, it is also not uncommon to find the movement of value added at constant prices estimated by means of changes in the compensation of employees at constant prices (SNA 93, page 397).

The conversion factor used in the National Accounts Statistics (NAS) in India is slightly different. In India, the base year estimates of value added from the banking sector are carried forward using an indicator based on the ratio of aggregate deposits for the two years and the wholesale price index (WPI). The volume of activity is measured in value terms, the indicator being the ratio of aggregate deposits. To obtain the quantity index, the ratio of deposits for two years is deflated by WPI.

It may be noted that the ‘quantity index’ of banking used in the NAS in India covers only one aspect of banking, i.e., deposits; other aspects like credit are totally neglected. This may turn out to be a serious limitation because the different products of banks are fairly heterogeneous in nature. A composite index based on activities of a bank would perhaps be more preferable. Moreover, deflation by WPI to derive the quantity index is tantamount to the assumption that ‘prices’ for banking move parallel to that of the goods sector as a whole, which may not be valid in reality.

Besides these simple indicators, models of real banking activity and measures for ‘prices’ and ‘quantities’ of various products offered by banks have also been developed in the bank regulation literature. To determine whether economies of scale exist in banking, researchers have estimated explicit multioutput production or cost functions. Typically, such functions include bank financial inputs and outputs, and the usual capital, labour and material inputs. Though precise measures of nominal and real outputs are absolutely crucial for such studies, a variety of approaches have been followed, and a consensus on conceptual questions has not yet emerged.

In the literature, three distinct approaches, viz., the asset approach, value added approach and user cost approach, are available. The process of generation of output and the role of demand deposit in all these three approaches are sharply different. Each of these approaches has certain advantages and certain drawbacks and adoption of any one of them depends on the objective of the study. A detailed discussion on all these approaches is beyond the scope of the paper.1 4

The paper restricts its attention on the user cost approach because a major focus in this approach is on measuring the implicit prices of financial intermediation through user cost (Hancock, 1985; Fixler and Zieschang, 1992; Fixler, 1993). The user cost approach attempts to measure prices of financial intermediation from the interest rates of different financial instruments. In traditional applications, prices of different financial instruments have been measured as deviations of the rate of return associated with them from a benchmark risk-free financial instrument (e.g., discount rates of treasury bill, coupon rates of standard Government bonds, bank rates, etc.). But the problem with this approach is that the estimates provided by it would be crucially related to the profitability of the banking sector. If the risk of default is high, banks might not be willing to disburse more credit as the amount disbursed might turn into a non-performing asset (NPA). If NPAs of banks increase, the effective returns from these assets would decrease. In such situations, the banks might tend to allocate a substantial portion of their funds in approved securities. Thus, if the profitability of the banking sector decreases, returns from advances would become closer to the return from the benchmark rates and for some periods, it might be less than these rates leading to zero or negative prices for some instruments. Alternatively, the weighted average rates of all asset and liability products of the banking sector have also been considered as the ‘standard’ rate.

In the Indian cont ext, Srimany and Bhattacharya (1998) have obtained empirical estimates based on traditional user cost approach and compared the results with alternative estimates. Samanta and Bhattacharya (2000), on the other hand, highlight the role of spread in this context. Their study demonstrates that under some simplifying conditions, the spread between rates of interest charged by the bank to borrowers and depositors could be given the interpretation of a price for financial intermediation.

III.2 Empirical Estimates of Prices and Output of Banking Services in India

In this section, we examine the behaviour of ‘price’ and ‘output’ of the banking sector from the national income data. Figure 1 presents the nominal (Chart 1a) and the real (Chart 1b) growth rates in GDP from the banking sector during the period under study. To compare the sector’s relative performance, these figures have been juxtaposed with the overall nominal and real growth of GDP in the respective parts. In Chart 1a, the

 

curves of NGDPGr and NBnkGr reflect the nominal overall GDP growth and GDP growth pertaining to the banking sector, respectively. Similarly, In Chart 1b, the curves of RGDPGr and RBnkGr show the corresponding values in real terms.

Using the nominal and real GDP figures, the implicit deflators in banking as well as for the entire economy could be obtained. These deflators could be used to obtain measures pertaining to sectoral and overall inflation. Chart 2 presents the implicit ‘inflation’ in banking services as per the NAS in India (Inf_Bnk). Once again, to compare its relative performance, these figures have been juxtaposed with (i) the overall ‘inflation’ in all commodities and services as measured by the GDP deflator (Inf_GDP), and (ii) inflation based on WPI (Inf_WPI).

It may be noted that the method adopted by India in preparing National Accounts Statistics is fully consistent with the international conventions. Given this, the above figures look strange. While it is expected that the growth rates in a services sector may be erratic and may fluctuate from year to year, such high fluctuation reveals the general methodological weakness in the convention adopted internationally. Is it possible that when inflation rates in almost all the sectors in an economy are on a declining trend, the banking sector experiences a more than 20 per cent rise in the prices and in the very next year experiences a deflation? We argue that the NAS is providing

 

a misleading picture because there is circularity in measurement of banking services. The circularity occurs because of the use of WPI to deflate the ‘nominal’ figures of the value added in the banking services, and that too based on solely the movements in deposits.

As an alternative, we examine the movements in spread-based measures. Although the theoretical implications of spread have been examined in detail, there is no unique empirical definition of spread. Brock and Rojas-Saurez (2000) have suggested six alternative proxies for banks spread, ranging from a narrow concept – one that includes

 

loans and investments in the assets side and deposits and borrowings in the liability side – to a broad concept, where all interest earning assets and interest bearing liabilities plus associated fees and commissions are included. In addition, one may perhaps consider the simple difference of a standard lending rate and the deposit rate as a proxy. In the Indian context, some of these measures have been computed and examined, sometimes separately across bank groups. For example, Chapter VII of the Report on Currency and Finance (1999-2000) defines spread as net interest income to total assets and computes this measure separately across bank groups from 1991-92 to 1999-00. The Report observes a gradual reduction of spread and attributes this reduction to competitive pressures. The Report also observes '…a tendency towards their convergence across all bank-groups, except foreign banks …' (pp. VII-1)

In addition to the measures suggested by Brock and Rojas-Saurez (2000), in this paper, we have considered three additional measures based on the simple differences between lending and deposit rates. As the interest structure during the early 1990s in India was administered, these measures are expected to reveal the extent of 'administered spread' in India during the same period. The definitions of these measures are presented in Table 9.

Table 10 presents estimates pertaining to the nine alternative measures of spread from 1989-90 to 2001-02. From Table 10, it is observed that there are strong correlations among many of the pairs of measures for spread. In general, correlations for pairs within a broad group are high and sometimes more than 0.95. However, in general correlations for pairs in different groups are moderate. Interestingly, measures in Group 3 have negative correlations with measures in other groups.

A detailed examination of these measures reveals that they are in general agreement with the observations of Reserve Bank of India. Almost all the measures display a decreasing trend during the second half of the 1990s. Thus, the spread appears to have decreased, implying a change in the price for financial intermediation. In this context, it may be noted that as during the early 1990s, interest rates in India were administered, the measures for spread during these periods may not reflect market forces properly and thus, may not be consistent with the existing

Table 9: Alternative Definitions of Spread

Group 1

SPN1=

[(interest earned on advances/advances)–(interest paid on deposits/

deposits)]* 100;

SPN2 =

[(interest earned on advances/advances)–(interest paid on deposits and

borrowings)/(deposits+borrowings)]* 100;

SPN3 =

[(interest earned on advances and investments)/(advances+investments)–

(interest paid on deposits and borrowings)/(deposits+borrowings)]* 100;

Group 2

SPB1 =

(interest earned –interest paid)/(total assets)*100;

SPB2 =

[{(interest earned)/(interest earning assets15)} –

{(interest paid)/(interest bearing liabilities16 )}]*100;

SPB3 =

[{(interest earned +commission, exchange and brokerage)/

(interest earning assets)} – {( interest paid)/(interest bearing

liabilities)}]* 100;

Group 3

SPI1 =

Lending Rate – Time Deposit Rate for Less Than One YearMaturity

SPI2 =

Lending Rate – Time Deposit Rate for One to Three Years

Maturity

SPI3 =

Lending Rate – Time Deposit Rate for Beyond Five Years

Maturity


market structure. However, it is interesting to observe that from 1995-96 onwards, all the measures of spread pertaining to the first two groups reveal a strong downward trend. Thus, it is logical to argue that as soon as the administered price regime in banking in India was lifted, the

Table 10 : Alternative Measures of Spread in the

Banking Sector in India: 1989-90 to 2001-02

Year

SPN1

SPN2

SPN3

SPB1

SPB2

SPB3

SPI1

SPI2

SPI3

1989-90

1.78

2.46

3.28

7.00

6.50

6.50

1990-91

1.77

2.43

3.32

7.00

5.50

5.50

1991-92

6.27

5.57

3.95

3.31

4.14

4.99

4.50

3.50

3.50

1992-93

4.81

4.63

3.67

2.50

3.48

4.33

8.00

8.00

8.00

1993-94

5.22

5.14

3.71

2.54

3.32

4.22

9.00

9.00

9.00

1994-95

4.25

4.24

4.37

3.01

3.65

4.59

4.00

4.00

4.00

1995-96

5.43

5.37

4.90

3.15

3.82

4.85

4.50

3.50

3.50

1996-97

6.29

6.29

4.86

3.22

3.85

4.82

3.00

2.00

1.75

1997-98

4.60

4.60

4.21

2.95

3.38

4.28

3.25

2.25

2.25

1998-99

4.19

4.26

3.85

2.78

3.15

4.00

3.00

2.00

2.00

1999-00

3.59

3.61

3.58

2.72

3.13

3.94

3.00

1.75

1.75

2000-01

3.74

3.78

3.62

2.84

3.18

3.91

2.75

1.75

1.75

2001-02#

3.05

3.22

3.15

2.81

3.10

3.82

3.25

2.87

2.87

# : Provisional for SPI1, SPI2 and SPI3.

favourable market structure put a downward pressure on the prices through competition. The result once again establishes that a favourable market structure alone may not be adequate for competitive prices and other institutional features and policy measures also contribute significantly towards it.

Section IV Conclusion

The paper examined the nature and the extent of changes in the market concentration in the Indian banking sector and their possible implications on competitiveness, prices and outputs of banking services. The paper was logically divided into two parts. The first part measured market concentration in banking in India in alternative ways from 1989-90 to 2000-01. In contrast to earlier empirical applications on banking, this paper focussed on both static and dynamic measures of market concentration. The paper found strong evidence of change in market structure in banking in India. Interestingly, results reveal that a major part of the change in market structure occurred during the early 1990s. Despite a spate of mergers during the late 1990s, banking market concentration in India was not significantly affected. It was also observed that different concentration ratios rank the changes of banking market concentration in India similarly over time. This result, in conjunction with Bikker and Haaf (2001a), provides evidence that despite the existence of a host of concentration measures, empirical rankings of countries over space or time may not be significantly affected due to differences in measures used.

The second part of the paper analysed the possible impact of changes in banking market structure on prices and output during the same period. It was articulated that before measuring competitiveness, the fuzzy issues relating to measurements of prices and quantities of banking services needed to be satisfactorily resolved. Using Indian data, the paper demonstrated that measurement problem of real output pertaining to banking sector in the national income data could be severe. The implied inflation as obtained through the GDP deflator for the banking sector in India led to unbelievable measures of inflation for banking services, casting some doubt on the methodology adopted. Alternatively, proxy price measures based on spread appeared to be more consistent with the changes in market structure in India during the late 1990s. The paper argued that the favourable market structure in India could be one important factor that led to a reduction in the ‘prices’ of banking services after

the administered interest regime was lifted. Although it might be wrong to attribute the entire change in spread to the change in market structure, it was logically one important factor that could lead to lagged reduction in the ‘prices’ of banking services in a favourable environment, freed from arbitrary price restrictions. A deeper study addressing these problems in a cross-country perspective would thus, be useful in narrowing the current gaps in the literature.

Notes

1 For example, the Report on Currency and Finance (1998-99) published by the Reserve Bank of India reports some of these indices and comments on the nature of concentration of export of the Indian economy (pp.IX.6).

2 For example, the survey of Bikker and Haaf (2001a) demonstrates that for 20 countries, the rankings of the k-Bank Concentration Ratios and the HHI are strongly correlated.

3 In the US, the Department of Justice, uses HHI to assess whether mergers and acquisitions 'significantly’’ constitute a threat to competition.

4 This is particularly so in the case of econometric studies of 'wage dispersion’’ in which statistical causes of dispersion are usefully identified, but welfare-theoretic motivation is lacking with regards to ‘‘dispersion’’ as a measure of 'mobility’’, or inequality.

5 In other work with PSID data, Maasoumi and Zandvakili (1990) have studied different weights, including Principal Component weights and unequal subjective weights. They find these weights are inconsequential for the qualitative inferences and rankings.

6 The taxonomy, in detail, is available in the 'Report on Trend and Progress of Banking in India', published by the Reserve Bank of India (RBI), for different years. These Reports also analyse the implications of the major developments in the Indian banking market in detail.

7 See the Box II.1 entitled ‘Merges and Acquisition in Banking: International Experiences and Indian Evidence’ in the 'Report on Trend and Progress of Banking in India 2000-01' (pp. 51–52) by the Reserve Bank of India for details.

8 The results based on other indicators at industry as well as bank-group level are available with the authors.

9 See Bikker and Haaf (2001a) for details

10 The rank-correlations among various indices also show similar results.

11 Results are available with the authors and can be obtained on request.

12 The structural approach to model competition includes Structure-Conduct-Performance (SCP) paradigm and efficiency hypothesis. The SCP paradigm investigates, whether a highly concentrated market causes collusive behaviour among large banks resulting in superior market performance; whereas efficiency hypothesis tests, whether it is the efficiency of larger banks that makes for enhanced performance. On the other hand, non-structural mod e l s

like Panzar and Rosse (P-R) model, uses explicit information about the structure of the market.

13 These types of indices have been applied to measure productivity of the banking sector. U.S. measures of banking labor productivity adopt the activity approach – bank output includes counts of loan and deposit activities (such as loan applications processed and cheques cleared).

14 For a recent survey of literature, see Srimany and Bhattacharya (1998).

15 Interest earning assets include advances, investments, balances with central bank, balances with other banks and money at call and short notice.

16 Interest bearing liabilities include deposits and borrowings.

References

Atkinson T. (1970): ‘On the Measurement of Inequality’, Journal of Economic Theory, II, pp.244-263.

Bain J. S., (1956): Barriers to New Competition, Harvard University Press, Cambridge.

Bain J. S. (1966): International Differences in Industry Structure, Yale University Press, New Haven.

Baldwin J. R. and P. K. Gorecki (1994): ‘Concentration and Mobility Statistics in Canada’s Manufacturing Sector’, Journal of International Economics, 42, pp.93–103.

Barth J. R. and R. D. Brumbaugh Jr. and J. A. Wilcox (2000): ‘The Repeal of Glass-Stegall and the Advent of Broad Banking’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14, pp.191–204.

Benston G., G. Hanweck and D. Humphrey (1982): ‘Scale Economies in Banking’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 14, pp.435–456.

Bikker J. A. and K. Haaf (2001a): ‘Measures of Competition and Concentration: A Review of Literature’, De Nederlandsche Bank, Amsterdam.

Bikker J. A. and K. Haaf (2001b): ‘Competition, Concentration and Their Relationship: An Empirical Analysis of the Banking Industry’, De Nederlandsche Bank (DNB) Staff Reports, No. 68.

Brock P. L. and L. Rojas-Saurez (2000): ‘Understanding the Behaviour of Bank Spread in Latin America’, Journal of Development Economics, 63, pp.113-134.

Calem P. S. and G. A. Carlino (1991): ‘The Concentration/Conduct/Relationship in Bank Deposit Markets’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 73, pp.268–276.

Chakravarty S. R. (1999): ‘Measuring Inequality: The Axiomatic Approach’ in Handbook on Income Inequality Measurement by Jacques Silber (Ed.), Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.

Davies S. W. and P.A. Geroski (1997): ‘Changes in Concentration, Turbulence, and the Dynamics of Market Shares’, Review of Economic Statistics, 79, pp.383–91.

Dean E. R. and K. Kunze (1992): 'Productivity Measurement in Service Industries' in ‘Output Measurement in the Services Sector’ by Griliches, Z.(Ed.), National Bureau of Economic Research, Studies in Income and Wealth, Volume 50, University of Chicago Press, pp.73–107.

De Bandt O. and E. P. Davies (2000): ‘Competition, Contestability and Market Structure in European Banking Sectors on the Eve of EMU’, Journal of Banking and Finance, 24, pp.1045–1066.

Diewert W. E. (1976): ‘Exact and Superlative Index Numbers’, Journal of Econometrics, 4, pp.115–145.

Fixler D. (1993): ‘Measuring Financial Service Output and Prices in Commercial Banking’,

Applied Economics, 25, pp.983–993.

Fixler D. and K. D. Zieschang (1992): 'User Costs, Shadow Prices, and the Real Output of Banks' in ‘Output Measurement in the Service Sector’ by Griliches, Z. (Ed.), University of Chicago Press, Chicago, pp.219–243.

Gilbert R. A. (1984): ‘Bank Market Structure and Competition – A Survey’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 19, pp.617–645.

Griliches Z. [Ed.], (1992): Output Measurement in the Service Sector, University of Chicago Press, Chicago.

Hancock D. (1985): ‘The Financial Firm: Production with Monetary and Nonmonetary Goods’,

Journal of Political Economy, 93, pp.859–880.

Maasoumi E. and H. Theil (1979): ‘The Effect of the Shape of the Income Distribution on Two Inequality Measures’, Economics Letters, 4, pp.289–291.

Maasoumi E. (1986): ‘The Measurement and Decomposition of Multi-Dimensional Inequality’, Econometrica, 54, pp.991–997.

Maasoumi E. and D. J. Slottje (2002): ‘Dynamics of Market Power and Concentration Profiles’,

Mimeo, Southern Methodist University, Dallas, USA.

Maasoumi E. and S. Zandvakili (1990): ‘Generalised Entropy Measures of Mobility for Different Sexes and Income Levels’, Journal of Econometrics, 43, pp.121–133.

Marfels C. (1971): ‘Absolute and Relative Measures of Concentration Reconsidered’, Kyklos, 24, pp.753–766.

Molyneux P., D. M. Lloyd-Williams and J Thornton (1994): ‘Competitive Conditions in European Banking’, Journal of Banking and Finance, 18, pp.445–459.

Nathan A. and E. H. Neavel (1989): ‘Competition and Contestability in Canada’s Financial System: Empirical Results’, Canadian Journal of Economics, 22, pp.576–594.

Neumann M. (2001): Competition Policy: History, Theory and Practice, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK.

Panzar J. C. and J. N. Rosse (1987): ‘Testing for Monopoly Equilibrium, Journal of Industrial Economics, 35, pp.443-456.

Pryor F. L. (1972): ‘An International Comparison of Concentration Ratios’, Review of Economics and Statistics, 54, pp.130–140.

Reserve Bank of India (Various Official Publications)

Rhoades S. A. (1995): ‘Market Share Inequality, the HHI and Other Measures of the Firm Composition of a Market’, Review of Industrial Organization, 10, pp.657–674.

Samanta G. P. and K. Bhattacharya (2000): ‘Prices of Financial Services: An Index Based on Spread’, International Journal of Development Banking, 18, pp.71-76.

Shaffer S. and J. Di Salvo (1994): ‘Conduct in Banking Duopoly’, Journal of Banking and Finance, 18, pp.1063–1082.

Shorrocks A. F. (1978): ‘Income Equality and Income Mobility’, Journal of Economic Theory, 19, pp.376–393.

Shorrocks A. F. (1984): ‘Inequality Decomposition by Population Subgroups’, Econometrica, 52, pp.1369–1385.

Smith R. T. (1998): ‘Banking Competition and Macroeconomic Performance’, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 30, pp.793–815.

Sen A., (1973): On Economic Inequality, Clarendon Press, Oxford.

Srimany A. K., and K. Bhattacharya (1998): ‘Measures for Financial Services: A Review with Special References to Banking in India’, Reserve Bank of India Occasional Papers, 19, pp.1–38.

Tirole J.(1988): The Theory of Industrial Organization, Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

United Nations (1993): System of National Accounts (SNA 1993 for Short).



Top